World's biggest 3 letter domain name marketplace
  • .com TLD
  • .net TLD
  • Lists
  • Promotions
  • Editor's Choice
  • Reserved
  • Add
  • Register
  • .com TLD
  • .net TLD
  • Lists
  • Promotions
  • Editor's Choice
  • Reserved
  • Add
  • Register
Search by typing & pressing enter

YOUR CART

The Dutch and First-price sealed bid auctions

DUTCH AUCTION


This auction is the converse of the English auction. The auctioneer calls prices in a decreasing way starting from a high price. The auction ends when one bidder accepts the price. This type of auction, rather uncommon, is used, for instance, for selling cut flowers in the Netherlands, fish in Israel and tobacco in Canada.

We will see that the main difference between the equilibrium in the Dutch and English auctions is that in the Dutch auction the equilibrium strongly depends on the bidder's guess about the others decision rules, while in the English auction the bidder's strategy does not depend on what he/she believes about his/her rivals bids. To better understand this difference, it is important to define the concept of Bayesian Nash Equilibrium.

* It is important to point out that eBay uses the term "dutch auction" differently. eBay's Dutch auction is a multi-unit auction for several identical goods to be sold simultaneously to potentially multiple bidders.





BAYESIAN NASH EQUILIBRIUM


For simplicity we will introduce the concept in the context of auctions satisfying hypotheses A1-A4 of page 1. A generalization to the general case of games with incomplete information is natural. Suppose that there are N bidders in an auction, with valuations v1,...,vN. The believes of bidder i about other bidders' valuations are independent of vi and they are the same for all bidders. Let's denote by V-i the set of all possible combinations of valuations of all bidders except for bidder i. A Bayesian Nash Equilibrium is a set of strategies, (s*1,...,s*N), that specify the actions of the players given their own valuations and such that for each bidder i, the strategy s*i(vi) is on average the best response, assuming i's rivals play according to (s*1,...,s*N). In other words s*i(vi) solves the maximization problem.

This definition might appear to be rather complicated because of the notation. However, a careful analysis of this concept reveals that it is a natural generalization of the concept of Nash equilibrium in games with complete information to games with incomplete information. Summarizing, in a Bayesian Nash equilibrium of an auction each bidder chooses his/her best bid given his guess about the decision rules being followed by his/her rivals (correct guess in equilibrium).
​

It is easier to understand the outcome of a Dutch auction by using the first-price sealed-bid auction.




THE FIRST-PRICE SEALED-BID AUCTION


This kind of auction has the same structure than the second-price sealed-bid auction described in the previous page, except that in this case the winner of the auction pays his/her own bid for the item. Unlike the English auction, bidders never see their rivals' bids and can only submit one bid. This type of auctions are commonly used for selling mineral rights to U.S government-owned land, and sometimes used for selling artwork and real estate property. Also, their analysis can be used to understand tendering of government procurement contracts.




EXAMPLE


Suppose that there are only two bidders in a first-price sealed-bid auction, labeled i=1,2. The two bidders' valuations, v1, v2 are independent and uniformly distributed on [0,1]. We claim than in this case submitting vi/2 is a Bayesian Nash equilibrium for each player i. For instance, for player 1 we have to check that v1/2 maximizes the quantity (v1-b1)Pr(b1 > v2/2), over all possible bids b1. This last expression is the expected payoff for player 1 if player 2 has the same bidding rule. From the definition of the uniform distribution this quantity is equal to (v1-b1)2b1, for b1≤ 1, and (v1-b1) for b1>1.

Hence in this case the bidder with the highest valuation wins the auction and pays a price equal to v(2)/2 (see the definition of order statistic). It turns out that the expected value of this quantity is 1/3, just like in the second-price sealed-bid auction. This is a general result that we will present in the next page.

We stated before that it is easier to understand the outcome of a Dutch auction by using the first-price sealed-bid auction. This is a consequence of the following theorem.




THEOREM


The Dutch auction yields the same outcome as the first-price sealed-bid auction.



It is quite easy to see why this is the case: in each auction the bidder faces the same situation, he/she has to decide how high to bid without knowing the other bidders' decisions, and if he/she wins, he/she pays a price equal to his/her own bid. Observe that this conclusion does not depend on hypotheses A1-A4.

    Price Drop Alert

TRACK PRICES

TLDs & Other

.com TLD

.net TLD

Lists

Promotions

Editor

Reserved


2 & 3 Letters

More Letters


Add your domain(s)

Register Domain(s)

Articles & Other

Chart

Options

F.A.Q

Traffic Analytics

Glossary

DNS Record Types

DNSSEC Record Types

2-Letter .com Domains

3-Letter .com Domains

4-Letter .com Domains

Useful Links & Tools

Contact & Other

Headquarters

IANA Whois

ICANN Lookup

RFC Editor

IETF

IRTF

NRO

APNIC

ARIN

DMCA

CC BY 4.0

Report Bug & Mistake

Policies & Legal

Acceptable Use Policy

Cookies Policy

Privacy Policy

Terms of Service

List of TLDs

Registrar Agreements

Acknowledgements

Subs

Dugrade (Down & Upgrade)

List (List Backup)

Expert (Register)

Service (Coming Soon)

Status (Operations)

Expiry Dates (Promos & Res.)

4-1.org (DNS Backup)

 Pay | 💳 AMEX | 💳 Mastercard | 💳 VISA
© 2025 | 0-4.org